Thursday, April 3, 2014

Territory, Agency and Globalization



                                                TERRITORY, AGENCY AND GLOBALIZATION

There is nothing more difficult to carry out, nor more doubtful of success, nor more dangerous to handle than to initiate a new order of things.
Nicolo Machiavelli, The Prince (1640)

Global Backdrop
            It is by now a cliché to suggest that globalization has changed the world.  Exactly how those changes are manifest is still an open question.  Still more important is the connection between global pressures and urban territories.  As we see it, globalization encompasses two phases—one of initiating flows of change and another of incurring its consequences.   A metaphor of this process could liken the initiating phase of globalization to a rapidly moving river while the consequences would be more akin to the river leaving sediments of deposit on adjoining land.[i]      
            We might say that globalization initiates rapid, intense, interaction across the world.  Initiation is dynamic and occurs at all levels -- technological, economic, political and social.   At the same time these flows have profound consequences for the spatial contours of cities. These consequences have permeated existing boundaries, shortened time spans and introduced what has come to be known as the “global village”.  
            Globalization is driven by a digital age which has sped up communication and radically augmented the distribution of information.  By the sheer touch of buttons over $6 trillion in capital is moved around the world each day (Goaswami, et al 2007; International Monetary Fund, 2010). Digital technology also moves news around the planet in unprecedented time and quantity. Media, like BBC or CNN, have established global news networks, allowing the world to witness the same events at the same time. Impressions are created instantly and reactions occur swiftly.
            On the economic-political front globalization is propelled by heavier flows of trade as well as cross national political agreements.   The flow between different economies is made possible by political agreements that facilitate currency exchanges, ease of travel, security guarantees and cooperation between governments.  The European Union (EU), the North American Free Trade Act (NAFTA) the Southern Common Market (Mercosur) and the Association of South East Asian Nations are just some examples of the international bridges built in recent times.[ii][iii]
            Taken collectively the increased flows of change have other ramifications. Once goods and common policies are absorbed on a worldwide basis they create a common transnational framework. International consumption is conducted through single currencies, uniform business procedures and standardized rules for patents, copyrights and passports.  Google and Nike not only elicit mass recognition, but do so with little reference to national demarcations. Even sports have drawn upon simultaneous global displays of the Olympic Games, “world cups” and tennis or golf “opens”.   Finally, globalization is spurred by social flows consisting of large scale immigration and cross cultural exchanges.  Over little more than three decades the number of immigrants has doubled and now includes 175 million people (3 percent of the world’s population).  Almost all of these have re-settled in advanced societies in Europe, North America and parts of Asia (UNDESA, 2002).
            The consequences of globalization for cities are equally compelling.    The digital age has made cities both unnecessary and essential.   On the one hand, cities have been rendered unnecessary because their strategic spaces were no longer suitable for manufacture.    Technology also invoked the “death of distance”, so that concentrating industry in a single center yielded few if any advantages.  Why bundle up within a single center when business can be conducted from office parks in nearby suburbs or from computer terminals in mountainside retreats (Webber, 1963; Klotkin; 2000; Weber and Kwan, 2002). 
            On the other hand, the essentiality of cities stemmed from the fact that the radical decentralization of industry evoked a complementary need to centralize their management, finance and coordination (Cairncross, 2001; Sassen, 2001).  Central business districts were born anew with smart buildings, hotels and convention halls. Cities may have lost assets when factories departed and all one could see were boarded up buildings, but they made up for it by their ability to connect things.   Post industrial cities were said to be “transaction maximizing systems” in an expanding universe of far flung factories, banks, retail outlets and warehouses.   London, New York, Hong Kong and Tokyo became leading, round the clock financial centers for the new “global village”. 
            Cities have come to be treated as belonging to different hierarchies and rated in terms of their centrality to the global economy as Alpha, Beta or Gamma cities (Knox and Taylor, 1995).   So keen became the inter city competition to advance within this hierarchy that local leaders often consult global indicators to determine where their cities stand.  In the wake globalization cities aggressively seek their “competitive advantage”.   The race has inaugurated a new industry of professionals offering to “rebrand” or “market” a city into fame.    For some the news has been quite good and a few cities rose quickly into the Alpha or Beta ranks.  But competitive advantage cannot be had equally by all.  The very idea of competitive advantage entails that some cities gain, others fall behind and still others may tumble out of range.  For every Austin or Singapore that rose to the fore, there also has been a Youngstown or an Essen which never managed to find a new post industrial life (OECD, 2006; EU, 2007).  Metropolitan areas also face widening territorial splits reinforced by social class and race.  In metropolitan New York the affluent buy mansions in the posh suburbs of Bronxville, leaving poor blacks and Latinos in the tenements of the Bronx.  In France’s leading metropolis, the rich settle in central Paris while North African immigrants and their children are shuttled into the run down public housing of La Courneuve.
            Last, we observe that the other side of global interdependence is local vulnerability.  Free trade may have made some cities wealthy, but they have also made them more fragile and susceptible to crisis. The fiscal crisis of 2007-08 made that all too apparent; in matter of minutes, turmoil on Wall Street upset finance in London that was soon telegraphed around the world.  Disease also travels as swiftly as airline flights and has acquired an international character (Savitch and Ardashev, 2001).  Aids, Sars, Bird Flu and even international terror threaten everyone with the same ease of movement and consequent pandemic.
            In sum globalization is an encompassing phenomenon. It is initiated by a multiplicity of flows ranging from technological innovation to free trade, political exchanges and the wholesale transference of populations. Its consequences are also multidimensional and punctuated by spreading urbanization, sharpening social rivalries, reactive political leadership and more vulnerable societies.  All this has profoundly affected the territory upon which these changes occur.  The meaning of the word “urban” has been rethought, the distinction between different types of landscapes has been reconceived and once impenetrable boundaries are now thought to be open gateways.  The central question before us is how far globalization has really gone in bringing about this new conception of territory, to what extent are new territorial conceptions valid and most important what does it all really mean?  To this we now turn.             
Globalization and Territorial Rescaling
            Scholars draw a ready connection between the advent of globalization and what has come to be broadly designated as rescaling.  In the interests of ecumenism, we treat rescaling as an embracing concept involving the reconfiguration or remaking of boundaries, sometimes carried out in combination with recognized governing institutions and at other times not.  As such rescaling has two likely applications, both of which are socially produced and geographically ordered.  First, it establishes physical or demographic demarcations of territory or what we refer to as informal rescaling. We see this as de facto rescaling brought about by scientific advances (communication, transportation) that change access to land, relationships between different land masses and the uses to which land is put. Second, is de jure rescaling brought about by the imposition of political institutions upon particular territories or what we call formal rescaling. Under formal rescaling institutions may not be contiguous with local economies or demographic realities and the new demarcations can either fall short of the mark and result in being under-bounded or go past the mark and cause an area to be over-bounded. In either case rescaling is very real because it imbues particular areas with certain prerogatives and responsibilities.  Most scholars agree that rescaling results in something which brings about a different state of affairs from that which previously existed. That “something” may vary from increased communication across spaces forming virtual communities, to coordinated transportation systems that knit together actual communities, all the way to regional councils that make policy for constituent communities. Whatever the form it takes, rescaling has profound implications for how territory is developed and can do many things to land.  In a figurative sense it has meant that territory can be reshaped, stretched or even shrunk. 
            When rescaling is limited to informal changes it can be expressed in a variety of urban forms.  We might see the retention of small unincorporated villages contrasted to the growth of urban agglomerations or we might see a metamorphosis of urban agglomerations into continuously urbanized land masses (London’s Greater South East Region or the BosWash megalopolis).  When rescaling is combined with an institutional embodiment it can be expressed in different ways.  Some types of formal rescaling include the fusion of separate localities into a single municipality (Toronto) the imposition of an umbrella authority over multiple jurisdictions (Minneapolis-St. Paul) the establishment of large regional councils (Lyon) and the creation of compacts between cities (Hong Kong).  Formal rescaling can also include changes in lateral relations between different levels of authority (Southern California Association of Governments)
            Returning now to how rescaling fits into the world arena, John Friedman’s (1986, 2001) groundbreaking work illustrates how global forces induce localities to reorganize space and shape political relations.[iv]  Friedman was later joined by others who sought to unlock rescaling’s mysteries.  Some writers took a few steps back to examine the underlying structures of a social order—hence their designation as structuralists.  Not easily seen, these factors consist of protracted, underlying (latent) dynamics that drive more visible (manifest) decisions.  For many structuralists the key to change hinges on economic system of a given time--or as they conceive it how wealth is produced, traded, accumulated or circulated.  Boiled down to its essentials, if economic conditions are based on simple agriculture and trade, territory is likely to be divided into small independent units (feudalism). Once digital economies take root, much larger assemblages of land are needed to facilitate the flow of capital. Structuralists have sought to interpret our global age as having surpassed manufacture, bringing about radically new ways in which territory is conceived and treated. 
            Braudel’s (1984) historical application of structuralism is pertinent here.   By using the grand sweep of history he saw the advance of capitalism expanding territory from a city centric to a state centric system.  By this stroke Braudel showed that economics not only gave birth to the modern state, but to a new version of territorial control.  The new historiography has its complement in Harvey’s Marxist geography.  Harvey’s own version of structuralism deals with globalization head on by pointing up the dialectic between the circulation of capital and the “compression” of increasingly large swaths of territory (1982). The faster the circulation of capital the shorter became the distance between different points on the planet.    Any gluts in the circulation of capital are dealt with through a “spatial fix”, where new urban landscapes (cities, airports,) are constructed to serve as outlets for investors (Harvey, 2001).   In language reminiscent of Einstein’s physics Harvey brackets together the speed of capital with the transformation of land usage.  Much as time could be changed by velocity, so too can territory be transformed by the passage of instant, globalized currency.
            Other scholars amplified this commentary. Swyngedouw (1997) crystallized this thinking by underscoring the nexus between global economic change and local decision making—hence his coinage of the term “glocalization” to describe this combination. Following on this, Brenner (1999) amplified the notion of “glocalization” by arguing that different economic cycles produced different kinds of territorial formulations.  His inquiry is framed as a probe into how “the current round of capitalist globalization has entailed a territorial reorganization” (1999: 6).  By Brenner’s account Keynesian capitalism produced fixed spaces that conformed to the needs of a welfare state, while a post Keynesian (neo liberal) period produced unregulated and unconnected spaces more conductive to a free global market.  Brenner then goes on to recognize formal rescaling, underscoring that spatial changes led to an “institutional scaffolding”, upon which governments could regulate and mobilize capital (Brenner; 2004: 447).  Michael Keating deepens the picture by pointing out that “as the state is penetrated by the market regional actors [are] forced into a more direct relationship with the external world” (Keating, 1998: 14).  Finally, Jessop (2000:35) put the cap on the structuralist bottle by describing these quick and mechanical adjustments as “reflexive rationality” where territorial units automatically recalibrate decisions in order to facilitate capital accumulation.
            Most evident in structural accounts is a conception of a system responding to an external stimulus.  Capital circulation produces new geographies with cities or city regions serving as its containers or as its processors. Governance is either greatly constrained to do capital’s bidding or relegated to a residual category.  For the most part its responses are automated and often described in the passive voice.   Thus we read that “the state is penetrated by the markets and territories are remoulded” (Keating, 1998:14).   The explanations appear to halt at this level with little effort to discuss who does what to whom.  Actors are hardly present in this scenario, much less is there any sign of, hesitation, heated debate or rejection of re-scaling.  Quite often, the process of change is automated and bloodless. Systems scale up toward bigger territorial control or scale down to smaller units of territory—all done to the dictates of economic necessity. 
            Another strain of thought, what we describe as eclectic, comes to similar conclusions, albeit by different methods and a different ontology.  Eclectic writers rely more on systematic data and are inclined to go beyond economics to embrace a variety of explanations.  Among the variables they cite are demographics, communications, infrastructure and culture.  Here too eclectic writers concentrate on abstract forces; glaringly absent is the influence of power and the role of institutions. 
            One of the foremost eclectic writers, Peter Hall (2009) takes a long view by analyzing how a variety of historical changes operate in shaping the contours of territory.  Hall too finds that territorial change will trend toward a single direction, guided and surmounted by the force of technology and the homogenizing effects of culture.  Laing and Knox (2009) join the issue by showing how massive demographic shifts contribute to the prevailing teleology.  Along with other researchers they point up that spreading populations lead to new settlements over a much enlarged landscape.  Change redounds upon change as expanded settlements warrant new infrastructure and new infrastructure generates still more development, which in turn changes the very morphology of cities.  By the 21st century traditional cities that were once identified by clear boundaries have become a thing of the past.  Old fashion concepts like “city”, “suburb” or “metropolis” are now considered to be “zombie categories” (Beck and Williams, 2003).   The new age calls for large polycentric, fluid forms where traditional distinctions blur and disappear.  As writers struggle to define this new “reterritorialization” the nomenclature swells to include a flood of neologisms like the “100 mile city”, the “urban realm”, “exopolis”, “splintering urbanism” and the loftiest of all titles the “galactic metropolis” (Sudjic, 1992; Vance, 1977; Soja, 1996; Graham and Marvin, 2001; Lewis, 1983)           
            In this post city era everything revolves around “space of flows” or “polynets” rather than territorial distinctions (Castells, 1989; Hall, 2009).  Having adopted this conception it is difficult to see territory as anything but a cipher for people communicating within particular networks.  Is all of this merely a set of processes? If this is the case, and most territories can also be converted into vessels of communication what then becomes of their relative importance?   Is one place interchangeable with another? Despite the fog, some writers have attempted to make something of new urban forms.  Neumann and Hull (2009: 783) find its tangibility in a “spatial-institutional isomorphism” that weaves together the governing capacities of disparate networks. Others search to identify how these new territorial complexities are governed, how they conduct politics or how they make policy.  Stoker (1998: 23) finds that “networks are self governing”. Like markets, he argues, networks bring self interested actors together through a type of fluid “governance”.  The remaining theoretical gaps are resolved by introducing the notion of “heterarchy”, meaning that territories can manage on their own.  Heterarchy describes the “self organizing” abilities of networks.  These explanations are left however as assertion with very little verification (Jessop 1998: 29). 
            What substantively occurs within these urban forms is not specified.     We are still left in the dark about the contents of “space of flows” “polynets” or “networks”.   Granted some of those who have written on the subject are geographers who are more interested in spatial dynamics than what actually occurs within that space.  In dealing with this issue we might distinguish between abstract spatial transactions and tangible changes on the ground.  But few if any writers of any persuasion draw this distinction, much less examine the linkage between spatial and territorial change.  Whether or not increased spatial transactions lead to territorial adjustments is still an open question.  More generally, how or why rescaling actually occurs is still unknown yet it remains vital to explaining the forces behind territorial change. Practically, nothing is said about the actors who make rescaling possible or about the participants who belong to these networks.    Over what kinds of issues are decisions taken and what about land use decisions?  What do we know about the substantive interests of citizens or investors or possible clashes between these parties? How are differences resolved?    Neither structuralist nor eclectic writers pay much attention to formal rescaling or the institutional moorings that might help us answer these questions.  The most we can make of ongoing accounts is that territory has engendered a life and direction of its own—reified as a thing unto itself and as an object of intellectual faith. 
            We suggest that territory does have meaning. Rescaling is not just fraught with processes, but with substantial issues and political implications. Territorial jurisdictions, political institutions and their boundaries cannot be swept away by conceptions of “splintered urbanism” or “galactic cities”.    The very ways in which territories are reconfigured and can open or close political and social paths.   In doing so, they shape individual behavior and collective action.  We all know that demarcated places are often commensurate with social class. Living in them profoundly influences life experience and social mobility (Dreier, Mollenkopf and Swanstrom, 2004).   Even very large territories like the American states  bear upon an individual’s ability to move up or down the income ladder (Pew, 2012).  Territory is power and like power everywhere it is used to obtain access, privilege, purpose, and instrumental ends.   To be sure not all territories hold this quality, but many do and we offer an alternative way of exploring larger ideas about the uses to which territory has been put.            

Putting Assumptions on the Line
              Scratch beneath the surface of the globalization/territory linkage and serious anomalies make it all very dubious. For one, globalization may not be the only source for much rescaling and it may have nothing to do with some of it.   As we shall see the roots of rescaling are complex and multifaceted-- not easily explained by any single cause or explanation.  Much depends upon how rescaling is identified, upon the places where it has been adopted and upon the circumstances of its adoption.  To say the least, rescaling has as much to do with pressures generated from inside a nation as it those external to it.    
            Second, the case that globalization has brought on the “death of distance” also may be overstated.  Small scale units are still useful and quite resilient as witnessed by the key role of central business districts and the longing for community.  The popularity of “new urbanism” and “neo traditional development” suggest that there may be limits to size and the utility of networks.  Adding to the skepticism, public choice scholars find that local jurisdictions continue to count a great deal.  Their logic is simple­­—localities maximize benefits by locking in positive externalities and minimize costs by locking out negative externalities.  Territorial identity serves the self interests of residents and by most calculations is likely to persist.  For this influential school any and all enthusiasm is reserved for either individual consumers or small territorial units (Ostrom, 2000).  While eclectic writers might overlay small units with new “spaces of flows”, much of this portrayal lies at the level of abstraction and little else.  In the United States and elsewhere small jurisdictions protect their own turf, which they see as holding the real action and pay scant attention to how they may be virtually connected to a different world.
            Third, if globalization exerts the pressures scholars claim it does, we would expect a great many cities to rescale.  Under these conditions we would certainly see an upsurge of rescaling from the 1980s onward.  While we are not aware of an empirical investigation that hones in on this specific question, our own work suggests this projection is not borne out (Tsukamoto and Vogel, 2007; Savitch and Vogel, 2009).  At least in North America and Western Europe the pre-global period of the 1960s witnessed a good many formal rescalings while the global era was relatively stable.[v]   Indeed, most localities have not rescaled nor are they considering it.   Rather, they continue as independent jurisdictions either competing with neighboring localities (United States) or functioning as semi vassals of central government (Western Europe, Asia, Latin America).  There are also instances where regional policies so popular during the pre global 1960s were abandoned during the global eras of the 1980s and 1990s.
            Fourth, if globalization engenders rescaling we would expect the most “globalized cities” to be eager candidates for such a change  While, some of these like London and Toronto have rescaled,  others like New York,  Frankfort and Milan have remained much the same over the last 40 years.  The idea that cities would rescale in order to facilitate the “circulation of capital” has very little basis in fact.  Certainly, the signs tell us there is no simple and clear relationship between rescaling and the requirements for the solvency of private capital.                    
            Fifth, if global pressures were the overriding source of rescaling we would expect similar patterns of response.   In point of fact, there are almost as many different forms of rescaling as there are cities that have undertaken that action.  Sometimes structuralist and eclectic expectations are borne out.  Hong Kong and its expanded linkages to the Pearl River Delta confirm a trend toward some kind of regional governance.  But at other times the exact opposite occurs and movements have arisen to reconstitute government into smaller units.  The secessionist movement in Los Angeles is a case in point and so too is the growth of greater localism in newly emerging cities like Buenos Aires and Santiago (Chile).   
            Eclectic writers might counter this critique by arguing that “spaces of flows” act to unify larger entities without a need for political institutions and formal institutions ought not to serve as the criterion by which rescaling should be judged.  But we see no systematic and consistent evidence to warrant that conclusion, and this pertains to both informal and formal rescaling. For every unifying act, one could equally point to actions that polarize localities and keep them apart from one another (Savitch and Vogel, 2006; European Union, 2007; Kantor et al, 2011).  The proliferation of cleavages not only holds for political divisions, but for social, cultural and demographic separation which appears to be growing (Putnam, 2000; Swanstrom, et al., 2004).  Nor should we equate increased commutation or communication across boundaries with social assimilation across boundaries.   If people are not joining with one another across boundaries, it may difficult to see where the “100 Mile City” is taking us or whether it truly exists.         
            Last, in the matter of theory it may be that that structure plays an important role in re-scaling.  Structures produce pressures that can have an immense bearing on how people act. But so too do people act and make decisions despite those pressures.  The human factor or “agency” which entails discretion, volition and circumstance should not be underestimated. Almost every territorial change involves agency of one kind or another—from the laying of infrastructure, to granting utility licenses and drawing boundaries.  Agency and politics allows for multiple pressures and cross pressures to exert themselves and loosen up structural constraints.  When it comes to reconfiguring territory, personal gain and even serendipity may count a great deal.   One cannot consider structure without appreciating how it is changed by agency.  To this we now turn.
Bringing Agency Back In
            We suggest that many of the existing accounts are incomplete; sometimes inaccurate; and, much of the time insufficient for explaining territorial change.   The terminology used to describe the process may not reflect reality and the metaphors employed may be overdrawn.  In the end “things” do not make decisions, people do and people enjoy discretionary space that can trump conditional constraints.  Put differently, we need to ground territorial rescaling in the reality of how people respond to challenges and act upon them.    As we see it, any such explanation needs to be considered in the context of human agency. Without this grounding the work already done on this subject loses its value.    
            Our approach is to inform global theory with experience from rescalings that have taken place in advanced societies in different parts of the world.  In a manner of speaking, we put existing interpretations under the light of grounded empirical research.  Like many other scholars we recognize that global pressures may act upon localities, but we also feel they do not function in a raw, direct manner or uniform fashion.  Here again local and in some cases national politics intervene to radically accentuate or displace global pressures.  We explore how political realities interpret, change, redirect, mediate, absorb or reject global pressures.[vi]  We illustrate the critical role of institutions and highlight that territory is not just a container for capital investment but an arena fraught with opportunities and obstacles through which power is exercised.   The implications are clear. Human discretion can shape territorial contours, using them to increase or lessen social polarization; political decisions can decide the permeability of borders, exposing or shielding the larger population to global forces; and, agency can determine territorial size, promoting or hindering human interaction across boundaries. 
            In short, agency can do many things, and we take as an assumption that nothing is necessary except that which is adopted and nothing is ordained except that which actually takes place.  It may be that rescaling will follow patterns claimed by theorists or it may be possible they will modify them or it may be conceivable they will reject global pressures.  This approach also enables us to fill the gaps in how territorial institutions actually work, both politically and socially.         
            Keeping this in mind we offer a set of propositions and themes. We take it as fundamental that rescaling shapes the content of political participation in different ways (Bachrach and Baratz, 1970; March and Olsen, 1989; Powell and DiMaggio, 1991).  This is particularly true of formal rescaling because it entails a high degree of organization.  In a word territorial institutions matter, and like all organizations they hold biases that tilt power toward some people and away from others.  For this reason alone it is important to uncover how institutions affect policy outcomes. Within these confines we also know that people make decisions under a variety of opportunities and constraints.  These can be complex and include 1) an array of interest groups as well as holistic expressions of popular opinion through referenda   2) the content of existing socio-cultural or political cleavages 3) the nature of a given regime sitting at the very locus of authority (city, region, province, nation) and 4) the motivations and objectives of elites who exercise power.  
            Beginning with the first theme, most studies show that territorial formulations are not deduced from global imperatives but are the product of interest groups and public opinion.   Interest groups have a great deal of influence on what is decided and whether support will be forthcoming. This is particularly true in the United States where success depends upon how a proposal is marketed and citizens are galvanized in support or opposition to a given proposal (Leland and Thurmaier, 2005; Feiock and Carr, 2006).  Indeed, in the United States consolidations, the adoption of metropolitan government and even annexation are subject to voter preferences.  In France, interest groups played a key role in how its National Assembly formulated a larger set of elaborate territorial rescalings.  Likewise interest groups or individual citizens may uphold the existing boundaries to protect their own advantages.  This not only holds for the United States but is quite applicable for Latin American cities which are typically fragmented by social class (De Mattos, 1999; Rodriguez, A, and L Winchester, 2001)
            Existing sociopolitical cleavages also matter a great deal in how territory is divided.  These divisions are manifest in informal rescaling and sometimes in formal rescaling.  One way or another, socio-linguistic differences are refracted in territory.  In Canada, interest groups were instrumental in how Montreal was formally rescaled, allowing Anglophone boroughs to opt out of its new territorial form.  In Belgium, divisions between Walloons and Flemish people have brought about an informal rescaling of Brussels (Hepburn, 2004).      
            In other instances of rescaling, political regimes are one of the keys to understanding how they come about and how they work.  Indianapolis’ “Unigov” as well as Greater London’s Assembly were creatures of new regimes that sought ways of reconfiguring metropolitan territories for narrow political advantage (Owen 1985; Newman and Thornley; 2005).   In each of these cases, higher level governments imposed an umbrella of metropolitan governance on an area.  Indeed, much the same can be said for Tokyo’s and Portland’s rescaling, each of which was the product of a political regime (Nelson and Moore, 1993; Vogel, n.d.).
            The last factor turns on raw power.  Since people who hold power often formulate how a territory will be rescaled, it may very well be that they are interested in maintaining power.  Our own experience with Louisville’s consolidation tells us that globalization had little or nothing to do with its rescaling and much to do with enhancing the control of local elites (Savitch and Vogel, 2004).  Power considerations also entered into the thinking of Marseille’s political elites as they decided to lead a confederative arrangement with surrounding jurisdictions (Donzel, 1998; Baraize and Negrier,. 2001). 
            One commonality underlying all themes is the ability of interest groups, regimes, elites or popular will to carve boundaries.  We can readily see that boundaries both circumscribe and enable the exercise of power.  Without boundaries power is clumsy, unwieldy and easily undermined.   With boundaries “authority” and hence “power” achieve resonance and can be channeled toward certain ends.   The notion that authority can be concordant with territory is a relatively modern idea which did not take root until the medieval period.   With the introduction of boundaries nobles and burghers began to set limits on each others’ power and the “rights” of different social classes gained greater traction (Weber, 1958; Sassen, 2006).   Quite often these boundaries were reinforced by the physical presence of walls and other obstructions, which more clearly defined what belonged to whom.        
            Those prerogatives gradually evolved and today boundaries make it feasible to set rules, muster resources, and distribute rewards.  The consequences are palpable. The modern day problem of how positive or negative externalities can “spillover” or “spill within” boundaries now occupies the thoughts of planners and other scholars.  Who gets the golf courses and who gets the sewage plants say a great deal about how boundaries draw the line between well being and distress.  Here are issues of lasting importance and we take them up in the chapters ahead.    
            Of course boundaries can be changed and are sometimes unstable but this varies with type of jurisdiction.  National boundaries have been very durable in modern times; state or provincial are also fairly stable; municipal boundaries less reliable and metropolitan boundaries are very pliable and often indistinct (Sancton, 2010).  Structuralists and eclectic writers often ignore boundaries, but we think that may be a mistake.   Whether boundaries are formed by networks of communication (informal rescaling) or the work people within institutions (formal rescaling) they continue to play an important role in urban life. .           
            In examining both the making of boundaries and larger aspects of territorial changes we observe that not all rescaling is as unicausal as the literature would suggest.   As we see it, territorial changes are due to a miscellany of motives.  Sometimes a single factor can overwhelm everything else while at other times multiple factors may operate singularly or in tandem and become determinative.  Given the plurality of experience, outcomes can take many different forms and yield dissimilar results.   Stemming from this we analyze how territorial power is acquired, the manner in which it is used, who turns out to win or lose, and what this means for a rescaled area.            



Grabbing Hold of Rescaling by Highlighting Diverse Cities
              Logically, we focus on the agency behind “territory and power” and the gravitation pull of this volume is toward formal rescaling.  While it is clearly not possible to cover a vast amount of cities, we have sought to maximize a variety of experiences and formulate valid propositions. Our concern with territorial institutions requires that we seek a large enough balance of cities to reflect differences in status, geography and type of city.   These cities are located in advanced societies within North and South America, Western Europe and Asia.  
            We opened this chapter with a discussion of globalization and it is also fitting that we select our urban territories by consulting indices of globalization.  One of the more comprehensive and up and up to date surveys has been done by MasterCard Worldwide (2008).  MasterCard identifies a set of 75 world cities, ranked by seven different political, business or intellectual indicators. Another well known survey was conducted by Global and World Cities (GaWC) project which ranks over 250 cities by their relative standing on how well firms within one city connect to firms in other cities around the world. By GaWC calculations different degrees of “connectivity” reflect how thoroughly a city may be globalized.     
            Our selection is geared to rank order listings of hundred of cities within these surveys.[vii]  Sixteen cities were chosen: the most prominent include London, New York, Hong Kong and Tokyo; those which are fairly prominent consist of Paris, Los Angeles and Toronto; those which are important but further down the global hierarchy are Montreal, Miami, Buenos Aires and Vancouver; and, those which have some consequence but are located at the bottom or outside the hierarchy comprise Marseilles, Manchester, Santiago, Indianapolis and Louisville. 
            Figure 1.1 displays a map of sixteen cities located in advanced industrial societies.  Our cities are drawn from across the globe.  MasterCard and GaWC rankings are designated for each city.  The symbols designate MasterCard by the size of the circle while GaWC is indicated by the color of the same circle.[viii] 

             

Figure 1.1.

Sixteen City-Regions Ranked by MasterCard  (2008) and GaWC (2010)
 


            These sixteen cities constitute the heart of our discourse and we draw from their very different experiences.  This broad sample makes up our data base and we recognize its   limitations as well as its advantages.  Naturally, our ability to generalize are bound by the cities at hand—all of them products of particular histories and a “thick environment” of local practices. At the same time we also see this as a way to capture texture and gain understanding that cannot be acquired by much larger samples and aggregate analysis (Weber, 1958; Gerring, 2007).  Our comparative emphasis presents opportunities for prudent judgment and that enables us to make educated evaluations about their applicability to other settings.  .        
A word should be said about style and method.  Our approach is thematic, discursive and comparative.  Rather than narrations of individual cities, we rely on a series of themes to trace the experience and consequences of urban territorial institutions.  For the most part, the analysis is done from the perspective of the central city and its nearby suburbs, and we refer to this composite as the “city-region”. [ix] The standard for the “city-region is fixed by the degree to which the central city influences and interacts with smaller jurisdictions around it.  In the United States and Canada the definition is concomitant with metropolitan areas designated by national censuses. Similarly designated “metropolitan areas” or “metropolises” are used for the United Kingdom, France, Argentina, Chile and Japan.  Because of its special legal and functional status Hong Kong is treated as a self contained entity (see Appendix for definitions and data). 
A comparative study of this kind warrants a methodological underpinning.  Any effort at linking institutional characteristics to particular outcomes poses considerable challenges, and in dealing with this we employ the conceptual tools found in a “theory of change” (Weiss, 1995; Savitch, 2011).   At a basic level the theory traces the lines between action and result.  It constitutes a way of applying explicit propositions to a potentially transformative situation and watches to see if the change occurs.  Phrased another way the “theory of change” focuses on the linkage between a priori theory (expressed in this case as strategic propositions) and a posteriori outcomes (demonstrated through case results).   The theory relies on the acuity of general propositions to expose the results of a specific intervention.  When applied to our own setting we should be able to establish a direct connection between promise and performance, say for example, a tangible connection between the initiation of a strong metropolitan unit to tackle sustainable development and a newfound capacity to preserve open land or build a waste treatment plant. [x]  If these changes do not follow from a promised innovation, we can only assume they do not work toward their intended direction.                 
                                                Thematic and Chapter Organization
            The material is organized into three basic sections.  An initial section containing this chapter and Chapter 2 introduces the subject matter and provides the reader with a background of the forces behind global re-scaling.  Chapter 2 discusses the importance of territory, political institutions and offers a theoretical framework for understanding how rescaling works.  A middle section containing Chapters 3, 4 and 5 serves as a topical umbrella for explaining the genesis and operations of rescaling.  Chapter 3 deals with monocentric re-scaling as it manifests itself in consolidation and multi tiered systems.  Chapter 4 takes up very different polycentric systems by analyzing diffuse (fragmented) systems where cities are either in full competition with one another or partially cooperate through “linked functions”.  Chapter 5 takes an altogether different tack by going beyond the metropolis and discussing rescaling at regional levels.  Here we examine larger the currents of regional development and prospects for intra regional cooperation.  A last section containing Chapters 6, 7 and 8 addresses the broader aspects of rescaling.  Chapter 6 deals with the role played by institutions in both initiating and resisting change. This chapter also deals with tensions between central versus local interests and territorial adaptations to those tensions.  Chapter 7 is more applied and takes up thorny issues about the actual impact of rescaling, namely the results it has yielded for urban development, bureaucratic efficiency and democratic accountability. A final chapter ties together our findings within the context of the urban future. Here we turn on several critical issues of whether localities can realize certain ends by territorial re-scaling, how can we best understand the effects of rescaling and what might be its intended or unintended ramifications.  Taken together these chapters offer new propositions about the uses to which territory is put.  We are able to show not only how re-scaling works, but how it fills the social order with political meaning.


REFERENCES

Bachrach, P. and Baratz, M.S. 1970. Power and Poverty: Theory and practice.  New York: Oxford University Press.
Baraize, F. & Negrier, E. eds. 2001. L’Invention Politique de L’Agglomeration. Paris, France: L’Harmattam.
Braudel, F. 1984. The Perspective of the World. New York: Harper & Row.
Beck, U., Willms, J. & Pollack, M.  2003. Conversations with Ulrich Beck. Polity. New York, N.Y.
Brenner, N. 2004. New State Spaces: Urban governance and the rescaling of statehood.  Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.
Brenner, N. 1999. Globalization as Reterritorialization: the re-scaling of urban governance in the European Union. Urban Studies 36 (3): 431-451.
Cairncross, F. 2001. The Death of Distance: How the communications revolution is changing our lives. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.
Castells, M. 1989. The Information City: Economic restructuring and urban development.  New York: Wiley-Blackwell.
Donzel, A. 1998. Marseille: L’experience de la cite. Anthropos Research and Publications.
De Mattos, C A. 1999. Santiago De Chile, Globalizacion Y Expansion Metropolitana: Lo Que Existia Sigue Existiendo. EURE (Santiago) 25 (76): 29-56.
Dreier, P., Mollenkopf, J. & Swanstrom, T. 2004. Place Matters: Metropolitics for the Twenty First Century. Lawrence, KS: Kansas University Press.
European Union. 2007. State of European Cities. Brussels, Belgium: Commission of the European Communities.
Feiock, R, Carr, J. & Johnson, L.S. 2006. Structuring the Debate on Consolidation: A Response to Leland and Thurmaier. Public Administration Review 66 (March/April): 274-278.
Friedmann, J. 2005. China's Urban Transition. Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press.
Friedmann, J. 2001.  World Cities Revisited. Urban Studies 38 (13): 2536-2536
Friedmann, J. 1986.  The World City Hypothesis.  Development and Change 17: 69-83.
Gerring, J. 2007. Case Study Research. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
Goaswami, Mangal, Jack Ree, and Ina Kota. 2007. “Global Capital: Defying Gravity.” Finance and Development Vol. 44 (1), March 2007. Accessible through http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2007/03/picture.htm
Graham, S. & Marvin, S. 2001. Splintering Urbanism: Networked infrastructures, technological mobilities and the urban conditions. New York: Routledge.
Hall, P. 2009. Looking Backward, Looking Forward: The City Region of the Mid 21st Century. Regional Studies 43 (6): 803-817.
Harvey, D. 2001. Globalization and the Spatial Fix. Geographische Revue 2 January 2001: 23-30.
Harvey, D. 1982. The Limits to Capital. Oxford: Blackwell.
Hepburn, A.C. 2004. Contested Cities in the Modern West. London, UK: Palgrave Publishers.
International Monetary Fund. 2010. Global Capital Flows: Defying gravity. Finance and Development 44 (1), March. accessible at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2007/03/picture.htm
Jessop, B. June 2000. The Crisis of the National Spatio-Temporal Fix and the Ecological Dominance of Globalizing Capitalism. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 24 (2): 323-360.
Jessop, B. 1998. The Rise of Governance and the Risks of Failure: The case of economic development. International Social Science Journal 50 (155): 29-45.
Kantor, P., Lefevre, C. Saito, A., Savitch, H.V. and Thornley, A. 2011. Global City Regions in Transition. Minneapolis, Minnesota. University of Minnesota Press.
Keating, M. 1998. The New Regionalism in Western Europe: Territorial Restructuring and Political Change. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.
Klotkin, J. 2000. The New Geography: How the digital Landscape is Reshaping the American Landscape. New York: Random House.
Knox, P. L. & Taylor, P. J. eds. 1995. World Cities in a World System. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Laing, R. & Knox, P. July 2009. The New Metropolis: Rethinking Megalopolis. Regional Studies 43 (6): 789-802.
Leland, S. and Thurmaier, K (2005) When Efficiency is Unbelievable: Normative Lessons from 30 Years of Consolidation. Public Administration Review 65 (4): 475-489
Lewis, P.F. 1983. The Galactic Metropolis. in Pratt R.H. & Mackinko, G. eds. 1983. Beyond the Urban Fringe: Land use issues in Nonmetropolitan America. Minneapolis, MN: Univ. of Minnesota Press.
Machiavelli, N. 1604. The Prince. Available at http://www.constitution.org/mac/prince00.htm
March, J.G and Olsen, J.P. 1989. Rediscovering Institutions: The organizational basis of politics. New York. Free Press.
MasterCard. 2008. Worldwide Centers of Commerce Index. Available at http://www.mastercard.com/us/company/en/insights/pdfs/2008/MCWW_WCoC-Report_2008.pdf
Nelson, A.C. & Moore, T. 1993. Assessing Urban Growth Management: The case of Portland, Oregon, the USA's largest urban growth boundary. Land Use Policy 10 (4): 293-302
Neuman, M. & Hull, A. July 2009. The Futures of City Regions. Regional Studies 43 (6): 777-787.
Newman, P. & Thornley, A. 2005. Planning World Cities: Globalization and Urban Politics. Basingstoke and New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 2006. Competitive Cities in the Global Economy.  Paris, France, OECD
Ostrom, E. March 2000. The Danger of Self-evident Truths. PS: Political Science and Politics 33 (1): 33-44.
Owen, C.J. & Wilbern, Y. 1985. Governing Metropolitan Indianapolis: The politics of Unigov. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
PEW Charitable Trust. 2012. Economic Mobility of the States. Washington D.C. Center on the States. April.
Powell, W. and DiMaggio, P. eds. 1991. The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago. University of Chicago Press
Putnam, R. 2000. Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. New York, NY: Simon and Schuster.
Rodriguez, A, and L Winchester. 2001. Santiago De Chile: Metropolizacion, Globalizacion, Desigualdad. EURE (Santiago) 27 (80): 121-39
Sassen. S.  2006. Territory, Authority, Rights: From medieval to global assemblages. Princeton, New Jersey, Princeton University Press.

Sassen, S. 2001. The
Global City: New York, London, Tokyo, 2nd ed. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Sancton, A. 2008. The Limits of Boundaries: Why City-Regions cannot be self-governing.  Montreal, CA: McGill-Queen's University Press.
Savitch, H.V.  and Vogel, R.K. 1996. Regional Politics: America in a Post-City Age. Thousand Oaks, California: Sage Publications.
Savitch, H.V. and Vogel, R. K. 2009. Regionalism and Urban Politics. in Davies, J. & Imbroscio, D. eds. Theories of Urban Politics, 2nd edition. Thousand Oaks, California: Sage Publications.
Savitch, H.V. 2011. A Strategy for Neighborhood Decline and Regrowth: Forging the French Connection”  Urban Affairs Review 47 (6) 800-837
Savitch, H.V. & Vogel, R. K. 2006. L’hyperpluralisme revisité: la poursuite de la fragmentation des villes aux Etats-Unis. in Jouve, B. & Gagnon A.G. eds. Les Métropoles Au Défi De La Diversité Culturelle. Grenoble: Presses Universitaires de  Grenoble.
Savitch, H.V. & Vogel, R.K. 2004. Suburbs Without a City: Power and City-County Consolidation. Urban Affairs Review 39 (6): 758-790.
Savitch, H.V. & Ardashev, G. 2001. Does Terror Have a Urban Future? Urban Studies 38 (13): 2515-2533.
Soja, E. 1996. Inside Exopolis: Everyday Life in a Post Modern World. In Soja, E. 1996. Thirdspace: Journeys to Los Angeles and Other Real-And-Imagined Places. New York: John Wiley & Sons. pp. 237-279.
Stoker, G. April 1998. Governance as Theory: five propositions. International Social Science Journal 155: 119-131.
Sudjic , D. 1992. The 100 Mile City. New York, N.Y: Harcourt Brace.
Swanstrom, T. Casey, C., Flack, R, & Dreier P. 2004. Pulling Apart: Economic Segregation Among Suburbs and Central Cities. Brookings Institution Metropolitan Policy Program.
Swyngedouw, E. 1997. Neither Global nor Local: glocalization and the politics of scale. In Cox, K.R., ed. Spaces of Globalization: Reasserting the power of the local. New York: Guilford Press. pp. 137–177
Tsukamoto T. and Vogel, R. 2007. Rethinking Globalization: The Impact of Central Governments on World Cities” in Hambleton, R. & Gross, J.S. eds. Governing cities in a Global Era: Urban innovation, competition, and democratic reform. New York, NY: Palgrave MacMillan.
UNDESA, 2002. International Migration 2002 Report accessible through http://www.un.org/esa/population/publications/publications.htm
Weber, M. 1958. The City. New York: The Free Press.
Webber, M. 1963. Order in diversity: Community without propinquity. in Wingo, L.jr. ed. Cities and Space: The Future Use of Urban Land, Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press: 23-54
Weber, J. and Kwan, M.P. 2002. Bringing Time Back In: A study on the influence of travel time variations and facility opening hours on individual accessibility. The Professional Geographer 54: 226–240.
Weiss, C.H. 1995. Nothing as Practical as Good Theory: Exploring theory-based evaluation for comprehensive community initiatives for children and families. In Connell, J. et al. eds. New Approaches to Evaluating Community Initiatives: Concepts, methods and context. Washington, D.C: Aspen Institute. pp. 65 – 92.
Vance, J.E. 1977. The Scene of Man: The role and structure of the city in the geography of Western civilization. New York, N.Y: Harper’s College Press.















                                                                        NOTES


[i] We define globalization is also treated in broad terms and as a process whereby previous economic, social, cultural, and political barriers to national interaction have become much more permeable.  As a result it is accompanied by a train of other changes, including radical deindustrialization, increased suburbanization, neo liberal economic policies and a push for regionalizing public policies.  In this chapter we treat globalization under these multiple rubrics.    
[ii]  While these pacts are regional in nature they constitute a significant step toward even broader international exchange.  Thus the European Union has grown from a handful of nations in Western Europe to include nations in East Europe and also grants privileged status to nations outside Europe.  Mercosur which operates in South America has begun to expand and even includes special status to Israel.  The EU has 25 members, Mercosur (Mercado Común del Sur) is comprised of four regular member (Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay and Uruguay) and five associate members (Bolivia, Chile, Columbia, Ecuador and Peru).  ASEAN is a loose association of governments comprised of ten nations (Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore, Thailand, Brunei, Myanmar, Cambodia, Laos, and Vietnam)

[iv] Since then and after studying China Friedman  has altered his position.  He now suggests we need to pay greater attention to internal political and cultural dynamics.   As Friedman states, “globalization as the analytical framework for the study of cities tends to privilege outside forces to the neglect of internal visions, historical trajectories, and endogenous capabilities.  It also places emphasis on economics to the exclusion of sociocultural and political variables. ( Friedman, 2005:  xvi)

[v]  In North America some of these included Minneapolis-St. Paul (,) Jacksonville (1967) and Nashville ( ).  In Western Europe the examples are London (1964) Paris (1968) Barcelona and the Randstad
[vi] Note the term “mediate” is often used in the literature to show how local institutions deal with globalization.  For us “mediate” is just one factor among many, and it may be that local institutions play a much stronger role in coping with global pressures as well as respond in multiple ways.
[vii]   Our sixteen cities are fairly well distributed along a range of categories and rankings. The Master Card Index uses the following criteria: legal/political framework, economic stability, ease of doing business, financial flows, business centers, knowledge creation and livability.   Using quintiles our sixteen cities are positioned as follows: first quintile (London, New York, Hong Kong, Tokyo and Paris) second quintile (Los Angeles and Miami) third quintile (Montreal and Vancouver) fourth quintile (Santiago)  fifth quintile (Buenos Aires) and not ranked (Manchester,  Marseille, Indianapolis and Louisville).  The GaWC index measures globalization more directly by employing a quantitative measures of connectivity whereby cities are ranked as Alpha ++ Alpha + Alpha, Alpha – Beta +, Beta -, Gamma +, Gamma, Gamma -, High Sufficiency and Sufficiency.  Our cities rank as follows: Alpha ++ (London and New York) Alpha+ (Hong Kong, Tokyo and Paris) Alpha (Toronto and Buenos Aires) Alpha – (Los Angeles and Santiago) Beta- (Miami) Gamma+ (Montreal and Vancouver) Gamma-(Manchester) High Sufficiency (Indianapolis) and Not Ranked (Marseille and Louisville)  
[viii] Both MasterCard and GaWC use central cities to compose rankings.
[ix] Our designation of the city-region is drawn from a previous work on the subject where we referred to this as the “functional city” (Savitch and Vogel, 1996).  
[x] Its roots as an evaluation tool are well established and the theory has been employed to assess a wide range of federal programs, most heavily in urban development (Abt Associates, 1997; Connell and Kubisch, 1998)







No comments:

Post a Comment